Skip to main content
Business LibreTexts

1.6: Thinking Like an Economist- Abstraction

  • Page ID
    88484
  • \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Economics, and its offspring, Finance, are abstract (social) sciences. In order to study economics, it is essential that one understands what an abstraction is.

    idea-icon-150x150.pngKey Terms:

    Abstract

    Abstraction

    Simplification

    An abstraction is an idea, intended to mirror reality in its simplest form. The world is a very complicated place; there are many variables or inputs, some identifiable, others not, that affect an outcome, and which we endeavor to identify. In order to understand the outcome which is generally true, but not necessarily absolutely or always so, one must engage in a process of simplification that requires removing minor variables from a general idea in order to reduce the notion to its essential characteristics. Indeed, the Latin word, “abstract,” comes from “drawing” or “taking away from.”

    The ever-changing kaleidoscope of raw reality would defeat the human mind by its complexity, except for the mind’s ability to abstract, to pick out parts and think of them as a whole.

    Thomas Sowell

    A Conflict of Visions (2002), p. 5

    idea-icon-150x150.png

    First Principles

    Ceteris Paribus

    All else equal

    In this process, one is able to derive a broad, general conclusion, based on first principles from which is derived a general idea or rule. In economics, this requires a ceteris paribus assumption, that is to say, holding “all else equal.” Initially, it is assumed that no other variables matter and are thus ignored away. It takes some discipline to do this at first, but it quickly becomes easy; you must merely keep it in mind.

    idea-icon-150x150.png

    Default Assumption

    Premise

    In circumstances where little given or known information may be at hand, one must assume reasonable default assumptions, i.e., premises, which make sense in general and in the simplest, most common form possible. While it may be facile to imagine other considerations, or variables, that may come into play, one must avoid doing this, in order to focus on just a few key variables, which affect the outcome. Here is a relevant comment by Dr. Milton Friedman[1]:

    A hypothesis is important if it “explains” much by little, that is, if it abstracts the common and crucial elements from the mass of complex and detailed circumstances surrounding the phenomena to be explained and permits valid predictions on the basis ofthem alone. To be important, therefore, a hypothesis must be descriptively false in its assumptions; it takes account of, and accounts for, none of the many other attendant circumstances, since its very success shows them to be irrelevant for the phenomena to be explained….

    idea-icon-300x300.png

    Dialectical Reasoning

    Mode of Reasoning

    Thesis/Antithesis/Synthesis

    To be sure, Dr. Friedman’s comments are not without criticism, but nevertheless are adhered to, by and large, in the social sciences, including, of course, economics. In certain other disciplines, including law, political theory, history, philosophy, and possibly others, we do not engage in this mode of reasoning. In these fields, by contrast, we are often engaged in dialectical reasoning. There, we first state a thesis, then examine its antithesis. We go back and forth numerous times until we can arrive at a synthesis, which is conclusive or dispositive.

    Those of you that are accustomed to dialectical reasoning must diligently avoid the natural instinct to quickly imagine the antithesis; rather you must remain steadfast to the line of reasoning demanded by the more linear manner of abstract argumentation, based on first principles and ceteris paribus delimitations. (A “delimitation” is a limitation that one person herself imposes on the scope of her reasoning.)

    idea-icon-300x300.png

    Descriptive

    Contextual

    Concrete

    Generalizable

    When, in certain instances, we deviate from abstract reasoning, we assume specific, more descriptive, circumstances in a contextual or “concrete” manner. The result may not be generalizable. If a conclusion is generalizable, we say that it is true in the overwhelming number of instances, although not necessarily all.

    One of the beauties of abstract reasoning is that it enables us to employ other, more reasonable assumptions when we find that a model has poor predictive power.

    Happy travels!

    Religion without science is blind, science without religion is lame.

    – Albert Einstein


    1. Friedman, Milton. (1953). Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. 14-15.

    This page titled 1.6: Thinking Like an Economist- Abstraction is shared under a CC BY 4.0 license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Kenneth S. Bigel (Touro University) via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.