What is central bank independence, why is it important, and why
do independent central bankers prefer lower inflation rates than
government officials usually do?
What exactly is central bank independence
(sometimes referred to as autonomy) and why is it
important? Independence means just that, independence from the
dictates of government, the freedom to conduct monetary policy as
central bankers (and not politicians) wish. Why does it matter
whether a central bank is independent or not?
Figure 14.2,
the results of a classic study, reveals all.
Note that as a country’s central bank becomes more
independent (as its independence score increases from 1 to 4), its
average inflation rate drops. The negative relationship is
quite pronounced, producing a correlation coefficient of −.7976.
The correlation is so strong, in fact, that many believe that
independence causes low inflation. (Correlation alone
cannot establish causation, but a strong correlation coefficient is
a necessary first step in establishing causation.) Some scholars
have argued, however, that the results were rigged, that
researchers simply assigned central banks with a good record on
inflation with a high independence score. (If this is true, it
would destroy the causal implications of the study.) While it is
true that rating a central bank’s independence is something of an
art, there are clear rules to follow. Where there is no rule of
law, as in dictatorships, there can be no independence. The central
banker must do as he or she is instructed or be sacked or possibly
shot. Little wonder, then, that many Latin American and African
countries had very high rates of inflation when they were ruled by
dictators.
In nations with rule of law, like those in
Figure 14.2,
it’s best to follow the purse. If a central bank has control of
its own budget, as the Fed and ECB (and some of its predecessors,
like the Bundesbank of Germany) do, then the bank is quite
independent because it is beholden to no one. The Fed is
slightly less independent than the ECB, however, because its
existence is not constitutionally guaranteed. (Indeed, as we
learned above, the United States had a nasty habit of dispatching
its early central banks.) Congress could change or abolish the Fed
simply by passing a law and getting the president to sign it or it
could override his veto. The ECB, by contrast, was formed by an
international treaty, changes to which must be ratified by all the
signatories, a chore and a half to achieve, to be sure!
Finally, central banks led by people who are appointed are more
independent than those led by popularly elected officials. Long,
nonrenewable terms are better for independence than short,
renewable ones, which tend to induce bankers to curry the favor of
whoever decides their fate when their term expires.
None of this is to say, however, that determining a central
bank’s independence is easy, particularly when de jure and de facto
realities differ. The Bank of Canada’s independence is limited by
the fact that the Bank Act of 1967 made the government ultimately
responsible for Canada’s monetary policy. But, in fact, the
Canadian government has allowed its central bank to run the money
show. The same could be said of the Bank of England. The Bank of
Japan’s independence was strengthened in 1998 but the Ministry of
Finance, a government agency, still controls part of its budget and
can request delays in monetary policy decisions. The current de
facto independence of those banks could be undermined and quite
quickly at that.
Stop and Think Box
“Bank of Japan Faces Test of Independence,” Wall Street
Journal, August 10, 2000.“The political storm over a possible
interest rate increase by the Bank of Japan is shaping up to be the
biggest challenge to the central bank’s independence since it
gained autonomy two years ago. Members of the ruling Liberal
Democratic Party stepped up pressure on the bank to leave the
country’s interest rates where they are now.” Why does the Liberal
Democratic Party (LDP) want to influence the Bank of Japan’s
(BoJ’s) interest rate policy? Why was the issue important enough to
warrant a major article in a major business newspaper?
The LDP wanted to influence the BoJ’s interest rate policy for
political reasons, namely, to keep the economy from slowing, a
potential threat to its rule. This was an important story because
the de facto “independence” of the BoJ was at stake and hence the
market’s perception of the Japanese central bank’s ability to raise
interest rates to stop inflation in the face of political
pressure.
Why, when left to their own devices, are central bankers
tougher on inflation than governments, politicians, or the general
populace? Partly because they represent bank, business, and
creditor interests, all of which are hurt if prices rise quickly
and unexpectedly. Banks are naturally uncomfortable in rising
interest rate environments, and inflation invariably brings with it
higher rates. Net creditors—economic entities that are owed more
than they owe—also dislike inflation because it erodes the real
value of the money owed them. Finally, businesses tend to dislike
inflation because it increases uncertainty and makes long-term
planning difficult. Central bankers also know the damage that
inflation can do to an economy, so a public interest motivation
drives them as well.
People and the politicians they elect to office, on the
other hand, sometimes desire inflation. Many households are
net debtors, meaning that they owe more money than is owed to them.
Inflation, they know, will decrease the real burden of their debts.
In addition, most members of the public do not want the higher
interest rates that are sometimes necessary to combat inflation
because it will cost them money and perhaps even their jobs. They
would rather suffer from some inflation, in other words, rather
than deal with the pain of keeping prices in check.
Politicians know voter preferences, so they, too, tend to err on
the side of higher rather than lower inflation. Politicians also
know that monetary stimulus—increasing the money supply at a faster
rate than usual or lowering the interest rate—can stimulate a short
burst of economic growth that will make people happy with the
status quo and ready to return incumbents to office. If inflation
ensues and the economy turns sour for awhile after the election,
that is okay because matters will likely sort out before the next
election, when politicians will be again inclined to pump out
money. Some evidence of just such a political business cycle in
the postwar United States has been found.See, for example, Jac
Heckelman, “Historical Political Business Cycles in the United
States,” EH.Net Encyclopedia (2001).
eh.net/encyclopedia/article/heckelman
.political.business.cycles. The clearest evidence implicates
Richard Nixon. See Burton Abrams and James Butkiewicz, “The
Political Business cycle: New Evidence from the Nixon Tapes,”
University of Delaware Working Paper Series No. 2011-05 (2011).
www.lerner.udel.edu/sites/default/files/imce/economics/Working
Papers/2011/UDWP 2011-05.pdf Politicians might also want to
print money simply to avoid raising direct taxes. The resultant
inflation acts like a tax on cash balances (which lose value each
day) and blame can be cast on the central bankers.
All in all, then, it is a good idea to have a central bank
with a good deal of independence, though some liberals complain
that independent central banks aren’t sufficiently
“democratic.” But who says everything should be democratic?
Would you want the armed forces run by majority vote? Your company?
Your household? Have you heard about the tyranny of the
majority?xroads.virginia.edu/~hyper/detoc/1_ch15.htm That’s
when two wolves and a sheep vote on what’s for dinner. Central bank
independence is not just about inflation but about how well the
overall economy performs. There is no indication that the inflation
fighting done by independent central banks in any way harms
economic growth or employment in the long run. Keeping the lid on
inflation, which can seriously injure national economies, is
therefore a very good policy indeed.
Another knock against independent central banks is that they are
not very transparent. The Fed, for example, has long been infamous
for its secrecy. When forced by law to disclose more information
about its actions sooner, it turned to obfuscation. To this day,
decoding the FOMC’s press releases is an interesting game of
semantics. For all its unclear language, the Fed is more open than
the ECB, which will not make the minutes of its policy meetings
public until twenty years after they take place. It is less
transparent, however, than many central banks that publish their
economic forecasts and inflation rate targets. Theory suggests that
central banks should be transparent when trying to stop inflation
but opaque when trying to stimulate the economy.
KEY TAKEAWAYS
Central bank independence is a measure of how free from
government influence central bankers are. Independence increases as
a central bank controls its own budget; it cannot be destroyed or
modified by mere legislation (or, worse, executive fiat), and it is
enhanced when central banks are composed of people serving long,
nonrenewable terms. Independence is important because researchers
have found that the more independent a central bank is, the lower
the inflation it allows without injuring growth and employment
goals.
When unanticipated, inflation redistributes resources from net
creditors to net debtors, creates uncertainty, and raises nominal
interest rates, hurting economic growth.
Independent central bankers represent bank, business, and net
creditor interests that are hurt by high levels of inflation.
Elected officials represent voters, many of whom are net debtors,
and hence beneficiaries of debt-eroding inflationary measures.
They also know that well-timed monetary stimulus can help them
obtain re-election by inducing economic growth in the months
leading up to the election. The inflation that follows will bring
some pain, but there will be time for correction before the next
election. Governments where officials are not elected, as in
dictatorships, often have difficulty collecting taxes, so they use
the central bank as a source of revenue, simply printing money
(creating bank deposits) to make payments. High levels of inflation
act as a sort of currency tax, a tax on cash balances that lose
some of their purchasing power each day.