How did the government exacerbate the Great Depression?
Time again, government regulators have either failed to stop
financial crises or have exacerbated them. Examples are too
numerous to discuss in detail here, so we will address only two of
the more egregious cases, the Great Depression of the 1930s and the
Savings and Loan (S&L) Crisis of the 1980s.
Generally when economic matters go FUBAR
(Fouled Up
Beyond All
Recognition in polite circles), observers blame
either “market failures” like asymmetric information and
externalities, or they blame the government.
Reality is rarely that simple. Most major economic foul-ups
stem from a combination of market and government failures, what I
like to call hybrid failures. So while it would be an
exaggeration to claim that government policies were the only causes
of the Great Depression or the Savings and Loan Crisis, it is fair
to say that they made matters worse, much worse.
The stock market crash of 1929 did not start the Great
Depression, but it did give the economy a strong push
downhill.stocks.fundamentalfinance.com/stock-market-crash-of-1929.php
A precipitous decline in stock prices like that of 1929 can cause
uncertainty to increase and balance sheets to deteriorate,
worsening asymmetric information problems and leading to a decline
in economic activity. That, in turn, can cause bank panics, further
increases in asymmetric information, and yet further declines in
economic activity followed by an unanticipated decline in the price
level. As
Figure 11.2 "Major macro variables during the Great
Depression"shows, that is precisely what happened
during the Great Depression—per capita gross domestic product (GDP)
shrank, the number of bankruptcies soared, M1 and M2 (measures of
the money supply) declined, and so did the price level.
Weren’t evil financiers completely responsible for this mess, as
nine out of ten people thought at the time? Absolutely not. For
starters, very few financiers benefited from the depression and
they did not have the ability to cause such a mess. Most would have
stopped the downward spiral if it was in their power to do so, as
J. P. Morgan did when panic seized the financial system in
1907.www.bos.frb.org/about/pubs/panicof1.pdf
In fact, only the government had the resources and institutions to
stop the Great Depression and it failed to do so. Mistake
number one occurred during the 1920s, when the government allowed
stock and real estate prices to rise to dizzying heights. (The
Dow Jones Industrial Average started the decade at 108.76, dropped
to around 60, then began a slow climb to 200 by the end of 1927. It
hit 300 by the end of 1928 and 350 by August
1929.)measuringworth.com/datasets/DJA By slowly raising
interest rates beginning in, say, mid-1928, the Federal Reserve
(Fed) could have deflated the stock market bubble
before it grew to enormous proportions and burst in 1929.
Mistake number two occurred after the crash, in late 1929
and 1930, when the Federal Reserve raised interest rates. A much
betterpolicy response at that point would have been to
lower interest rates in order to help troubled banks and stimulate
business investment and hence private job growth. In addition,
the Federal Reserve did not behave like a lender of last
resort (LLR) during the crisis and follow
Bagehot’s/Hamilton’s Rule. Before the Fed began
operations in the fall of 1914, regional
clearinghouses had acted as LLRs, but during the
Depression they assumed, wrongly as it turned out, that the Fed had
relieved them of that responsibility. They were, accordingly,
unprepared to thwart major bank runs.Michael Bordo and David
Wheelock, “The Promise and Performance of the Federal Reserve as
Lender of Last Resort,” Norges Bank Working Paper 201 (20 January
2011). papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1847472
The government’s third mistake was its banking policy.
The United States was home to tens of thousands of
tiny unit banks that simply were not large or diversified enough to
ride out the depression. If a factory or other major employer
succumbed, the local bank too was doomed. Depositors understood
this, so at the first sign of trouble they ran on their banks,
pulling out their deposits before they went under. Their actions
guaranteed that their banks would indeed fail. Meanwhile, across
the border in Canada, which was home to a few large and highly
diversified banks, few bank disturbances took place. California
also weathered the Great Depression relatively well, in part
because its banks, which freely branched throughout the large
state, enjoyed relatively well-diversified assets and hence avoided
the worst of the bank crises.
The government’s fourth failure was to raise tariffs in a
misguided attempt to “beggar thy
neighbor.”www.state.gov/r/pa/ho/time/id/17606.htm
Detailed analysis of this failure, which falls outside the
bailiwick of finance, I’ll leave to your international economics
textbook and a case elsewhere in this book. Here, we’ll just
paraphrase Mr. Mackey from South Park: “Tariffs are bad,
mmmkay?”en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_staff_at_South_Park_Elementary#Mr._Mackey
But what about Franklin Delano Roosevelt
(FDR)www.whitehouse.gov/history/presidents/fr32.html and his
New Deal?newdeal.feri.org Didn’t the new administration stop
the Great Depression, particularly via deposit insurance,
Glass-Steagall, securities market reforms, and reassuring speeches
about having nothing to fear but fear itself?historymatters.gmu.edu/d/5057 The United States
did suffer its most acute banking crisis in March 1933, just as FDR
took office on March 4.www.bartleby.com/124/pres49.html
(The Twentieth Amendment, ratified in 1938, changed the
presidential inauguration date to January 20, which it is to this
day.) But many suspect that FDR himself brought the crisis on by
increasing uncertainty about the new administration’s policy path.
Whatever the cause of the crisis, it shattered confidence in
the banking system. FDR’s creation of a deposit insurance scheme
under the aegis of a new federal agency, the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC), did restore confidence, inducing
people to stop running on the banks and thereby stopping the
economy’s death spiral. Since then, bank runs have been rare
occurrences directed at specific shaky banks and not system-wide
disturbances as during the Great Depression and earlier banking
crises.
But as with everything in life, deposit insurance is far
from cost-free. In fact, the latest research suggests it is a
wash. Deposit insurance does prevent bank runs because
depositors know the insurance fund will repay them if their bank
goes belly up. (Today, it insures $250,000 per depositor per
insured bank. For details, browsewww.fdic.gov/deposit/deposits/insured/basics.html)
However, insurance also reduces depositor monitoring, which allows
bankers to take on added risk. In the nineteenth century,
depositors disciplined banks that took on too much risk by
withdrawing their deposits. As we’ve seen, that decreases the size
of the bank and reduces reserves, forcing bankers to decrease their
risk profile. With deposit insurance, depositors (quite rationally)
blithely ignore the adverse selection problem and shift their funds
to wherever they will fetch the most interest. They don’t ask how
Shaky Bank is able to pay 15 percent for six-month certificates of
deposit (CDs) when other banks pay only 5 percent. Who cares, they
reason, my deposits are insured! Indeed, but as we’ll learn below,
taxpayers insure the insurer.
Another New Deal financial reform, Glass-Steagall, in no way
helped the U.S. economy or financial system and may have hurt
both. For over half a century, Glass-Steagall prevented U.S.
banks from simultaneously engaging in commercial (taking deposits
and making loans) and investment banking (underwriting securities
and advising on mergers) activities. Only two groups clearly gained
from the legislation, politicians who could thump their chests on
the campaign stump and claim to have saved the country from greedy
financiers and, ironically enough, big investment banks. The
latter, it turns out, wrote the act and did so in such a way that
it protected their oligopoly from the competition of commercial
banks and smaller, more retail-oriented investment banks. The act
was clearly unnecessary from an economic standpoint because most
countries had no such legislation and suffered no ill effects
because of its absence. (The Dodd-Frank Act’s Volcker Rule
represents a better approach because it outlaws various dubious
practices, like proprietary trading, not valid
organizational forms).
The Security and Exchange Commission’s (SEC) genesis is
almost as tawdry and its record almost as bad. The SEC’s
stated goal, to increase the transparency of America’s financial
markets, was a laudable one. Unfortunately, the SEC simply does not
do its job very well. As the late, great, free-market proponent
Milton Friedman put it:
“You are not free to raise funds on the capital marketsThis part
is inaccurate. Financiers went loophole mining and found a real
doozy called a private placement. As opposed to a public offering,
in a private placement securities issuers can avoid SEC disclosure
requirements by selling directly to institutional investors like
life insurance companies and other “accredited investors” (legalese
for “rich people”). unless you fill out the numerous pages of forms
the SEC requires and unless you satisfy the SEC that the prospectus
you propose to issue presents such a bleak picture of your
prospects that no investor in his right mind would invest in your
project if he took the prospectus literally.This part is all too
true. Check out the prospectus of Internet giant Google at
www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/1288776/000119312504142742/ds1a.htm.
If you don’t dig Google, check out any company you like via Edgar,
the SEC’s filing database, at www.sec.gov/edgar.shtml.
And getting SEC approval may cost upwards of $100,000—which
certainly discourages the small firms our government professes to
help.”
Stop and Think Box
As noted above, the FDIC insures bank deposits up to $250,000
per depositor per insured bank. What if an investor wants
to deposit $1 million or $1 billion? Must the investor put most of
her money at risk?
Depositors can loophole mine as well as anyone. And they did,
or, to be more precise, intermediaries known as deposit brokers
did. Deposit brokers chopped up big deposits into insured-sized
chunks, then spread them all over creation. The telecommunications
revolution made this relatively easy and cheap to do, and the
S&L crisis created many a zombie bank willing to pay high
interest for deposits.
KEY TAKEAWAYS
In addition to imposing high
tariffs, the government exacerbated the Great Depression by (1)
allowing the asset bubble of the late 1920s to continue; (2)
responding to the crash inappropriately by raising the interest
rate and restricting M1 and M2; and (3) passing reforms of dubious
long-term efficacy, including deposit insurance, Glass-Steagall,
and the SEC.